Although not being a homogenous theory, most papers and scholars
related to MMT share some views and concepts. I willl briefly
describe some components and critically comment them. This is insofar
a risky endeavor as I am not coming from “inside” MMT but being
a curious and open-minded economist, open also for heterodox ideas,
though having difficulties in understanding what the “T” in MMT
really is. Moreover, MMT stems from Post-Keynesian (PK) economics and
thus sharing the legacy of a tradition to create its own, partially
incommensurable terminology and to reject critique by asserting that
it is based on a misunderstanding. Anyway, I have nothing to lose, so
here is my critical summary from a personal point of view. Each point
starts with an important MMT element (in Italics) which is then
discussed.
1) Banks are not
channeling funds from savers to investors, hence the “Loanable
Funds Theory” (LFT) is flawed. Instead, deposits (money) are
created by banks by providing credits or buying bonds
from non-banks. This induces a demand for reserves
which can be created by the central bank only. The central bank (CB)
will fully accommodate the demand for reserves as their
primary operating tool is the interest rate. If CB
would try to “control” the monetary base it would lose control
over the short-run interest rate. Thus, money is something endogenous
while the short-run rate is controlled by the CB. The
famnous “money multiplier” is just an algebraic relationship but
the story one can find in old and outdated textbooks that the CB
does not only determine M0 but also M via the
multiplier, is flawed. The causality runs the other way round.
I fully agree!
However, this view is mainstream and not specific to MMT. This is
part of my courses since years even before I ever heard about “MMT”.
One can find it in standard textbooks as well as in publications e.g.
of the Deutsche Bundesbank or the Bank of England. It is also the
main reason why in modern New Keynesian macroeconomics the old LM
curve is replaced by an interest rate rule of the CB. It has always
been a puzzle for me why the simple description of daily acounting
practices of banks is a scientific “discovery” and a “theory”
how money is created. Anyway, it is good that somebody enunciates
that.
But there are some
caveats:
- One should keep in mind that “full accomodation” of reserve demand is a behavioral trait of most central banks around the world which are committed to Inflation Targeting. If, for example, a CB would adopt a position where interest rates are just a market price while the operative goal is to control M, things would be different. So the MMT view is a correct description of the current fractional reserve banking system and the current paradigm of practical CB policies. But it would become inappropriate if this paradigm would change. Example: before the Global Financial Crisis, the ECB and fomerly the Deutsche Bundesbank did not guarantee a “full allotment” when commercial banks applied for central bank credits.
- In MMT, the Post-Keynesian “horizontalist position” is adopted: commercial bank’s credit supply is fully elastic, thus the money volume is only determined by money demand. But there is no need for this oversimplisric view. Considering technical details of loan creation such like calculating risk premia, collateralization, credit risk standards, maturity mismatch effects, capital constraints, portfolio balancing effects etc., also upwards sloped credit supply curves and rationing effects could be considered. Thus, the long-run interest rate for risky assets which is highly important for decisions in the real sector, is just “influenced” by the CB but not determined. Mainstream financial economics have much more elaborated models of banking’s credit supply behavior than the “horizontalist approach”.
- With the enormously grown shadow-banking sector, commercial banks have alternatives to borrow liquidity which influences their demand for reserves. Moreover, the interest-rate strategy of CBs is typically anchored at a “natural rate”. These arguments give reason to believe that even the short-run rate is not purely exogenously determined by the central bank, but in a certain sense the CB is also following a long-run market developments.
- There is meanwhile a huge amount of credits provided by “shadow banks”, i.e. finance companies. Here, the LFT fully applies: these financial institutions issue papers in order to raise funds which are then lend out. One should keep in mind that this sector provides a quite close substitute to “normal” credits by depository banks. And this has an impact on the long-term rate which is also targeted by the CB. A realistic model of the financial market (and thus monetary policy transmission) has to take this into consideration.
- The rejection of LFT is often expressed by the claim that “banks are not intermediates”. This is true only in the sense that they do not channel resources from A to B. But they could be considered as intermediates as they are doing asset transformation (lot size, maturity, risk, liquidity transformation) and partially solving or mitigating principal-agent problems. In this sense I (and many textbooks) still use the term “intermediate”.
2) Fiscal
expenditures are operated by the central bank by creating money while
tax revenues are reducing money. Thus, one should think about the
fiscal and monetary operations as one unit. Fiscal expenditures have
therefore not to be “financed” by (current or future)
taxes, and the fiscal budget is not “constrained”.
The budget is G + iD = T + ΔD
+ ΔM, and
it is a decision of the “sovereign state” to decide about these
components. [G = gov. expenditures, D = public debt (bonds), T
= tax revenues, M = money (own currency), i = interest rate on public
debt]
Yes, MMT is right
when saying that in daily practice (!) fiscal expenditures are
operated by the central bank just by creating and transferring
money. There is a permanent flow of governmental expenditures and
also a permanent inflow of taxes and inflow of money as a result of
issuing bonds. As this is not perfectly synchronized, we see on the
central bank’s balance sheet a permanent creation and destruction
of money. That is a description of accounting practice,
not a “theory”. I cannot see this as a “scientific point of
view”. And nothing specific follows from this practice. Imagine,
that the same operations are done by a commerical bank which is
willing to handle the government’s budget. The ΔM
in the equation is then the government’s bank credit which has
created additional deposits. But in this case it would become evident
that there is a (limited) credit line, and a credit has to be served
and paid back. Insofar there is a constraint by tax revenues, the
ability to place new bonds (which also have to be served and paid
back), and the bank’s credit line. The MMT’s semantic that – in
contrast to a private household which doesn’t have an account at
the central bank – governmental expenditures do not have to be
“financed” and that there are no constraints, is more confusing
than clarifying the operations. It is better to say that expenditures
have not to be “pre-financed” by taxes. And it is
legitimate to say that the fiscal authority is “not constrained”
in the expenditures if and only if the legislation allows for
unlimited monetization of public debt. But the latter is not the case
in most countries, and the (non) allowance doesn’t follow from the
accounting practice. Likewise the claims about the endogeneity of
money and the accomodative behavior of CBs are grounded in the
observed (legal) practice, MMT should also respect the legal practice
of non-allowance of monetization of public debt in most countries.
The thing is now
that MMT rejects this practice and declare the opposite as the
“natural state” and also as a normative benchmark:
3) A sovereign
state which is able to issue its own currency can never get
insolvent. This is because one have to think fiscal and monetary
operations as one unit (see above). Henceforth, the government could
do everything necessary to manage aggregate demand wthout being
constrained by the budget, without being dependent on the private
capital market, and thus without any risk to get insolvent.
Yes, MMT is
completely right – but only in a ficticious world where unlimited
monetization of public debt is allowed which implies that central
banks are not independent. Consequently, MMT offers explanations of
macroeconomic problems arising from institutional arrangements where
the state isn’t “sovereign”, i.e. if central banks are
independent, or even worse, if national fiscal policies cannot be
coordinated with a supranational monetary policy like in the case of
the Eurozone which is seen as dysfunctional construction.
In which sense this
is “theory”? Or is it more a political suggestion, an agenda how
to design monetary and fiscal institutions and rules? The clause “If
sovereign … then not constrained” sounds like a theory but
it isn’t much more than a tautology as MMT proposes a new semantic
what “sovereign” means. As the term implies total “fiscal
dominance” (in mainstream terms) or unlimited automatic bailout,
the theoretical claim that a sovereign state cannot get insolvent (if
indebted in domestic currency) is a tautology or at least trivial. In
this sense, neither the Eurozone countries, nor e.g. Germany at times
of the Deutsche Mark are considered as sovereign countries – thus,
the MMT view is confirmed. The narrative is always confirmed.
That’s the problem rather than the advantage.
What is really
annoying is that MMT largely ignores the literature of the last
decades about time-inconsistency and principal-agent problems, the
role of credibility in monetary policy transmission, the political
economy of (fiscal) policy making in democracies, also some empirical
issues such like the fact that nearly all episodes of hyper-inflation
occurred in systems with unlimited monetization of public debt. Thus,
they are largely ignoring economic arguments in favor e.g. of CB
independence. It appears as if the “mainstream” wasted an
enormous amount of time and human capital in the last decades in
order to analyse problems which would not exist if neoliberal
mainastream economists would not have pushed policy to make states
being non-sovereign.
Instead, the MMT
view is surprisingly super-simple: the government is benevolent,
omnipotent, and has just to manage aggregate demand in order to heal
nearly every macroeconomic problem because nearly all problems stem
from the demand side. And the necessary fiscal opetrations are
unconstrained thanks to the CB which is accomodating any fiscal
budget, if necessary by creating money. From this point of view, all
deviating positions which are summarized as “mainstream” are thus
blamed as being “neoliberal ideologies” or based on naive
perceptions of a “Swabian housewife” (making it difficult to
really communicate with economists outside the own bubble).
The wording, the own
semantic, the ignorance of large parts of the literature contributes
a lot to the picture that MMT is more a cult rather than a serious
theory. That’s a pity because some elements could contribute to
scientific progress. The ideological pride to be “non-mainstream”,
and adopting the Post-Keynesian academic legacy which is best
characterized by Monty Python’s “Life of Brian” where
the biggest enemy of the Judean
People’s Front is
the People’s Front of Judea, also
hinders MMT to be recognized as a potentially
valuable
academic contribution.
4)
Debt of one entity are claims (or wealth) of the other. Hence,
public debt is (part of) private wealth.Also expenditures of
one entity are income of the other.
I
cannot believe that this triviality is regarded to be an “insight”
of a “scientific theory”. This
is part of an economics 101 course when describing
the national accounting system.
5)
An
open economy like Germany cannot permanently run a trade surplus and
having a balanced fiscal budget. They
are forcing other
countries to
get more and more indebted. So if the private sector has a “surplus”,
and trade should be balanced in the long run, the governemnt must run
a deficit. Therefore debt brakes and the ideology of “balanced
budgets” (like the “Swabian housewife”) are undermining
macroeconomic stability. The “German strategy” to run balanced
fiscal budgets and to achieve a trade surplus at
the same time is
a “neo-merkantilist” strategy which cannot be recommended.
It
requires that there are deficit countries, willing to get more and
more indebted.
Usually,
this argument is explained by excessively re-iterating the national
book-keeping equation S
= I + Ex – Im
in various forms, and disentangling private and public savings: S
= Sp
+ (T – G).
However, an algebraic relationship from national accounting system
isn’t yet a theory. All conclusions one can directly
draw
from it, are trivial. Of
course a large and permanent trade surplus might be problematic in
terms of macroeconomic equilibrium.
Many economists and international institutions are concerned about
the German surplus,
even without any reference to MMT. However, the intertemporal
approach to the balance of payments shows
that trade imbalances (for a certain time) could be efficient
for both
trade partners. Unfortunately,
the terms “surplus” and “deficit” have a strong normative
connotation.
The
claim of a “German strategy” which is “neo-merkantilist”
suggests that the country is acting just like one economic unit,
instead of considering
millions
of single (domestic
and
foreign)
economic
decisions. Or it
suggests that
the government is able to strategically determine the overall
empirical
picture. For example, the success of the German export sector is
explained by too low wages. Although
there might be some truth in this argument, it neglects
that also other factors such like high productivity and/or high
quality might also play a role. Wages are contracted, not
set by the government. However, there might be indirect effects such
like dampening
the wage dynamics through Agenda 2010 labor market reforms. But the
goal of these reforms have been the reduction of unemployment rather
than “neo-merkantilist” goals. The
former is achieved while the trade surplus might be seen as an
unwarranted side effect.
So
if in the long run (Ex
– Im)
should be close to zero, and the private sector runs a “surplus”
Sp
– I > 0,
then it is seen
as necessary
that the government runs a deficit T
– G < 0.
However, this is algebra, not theory, and no policy
agenda follows from that. A supply side economist would argue that
policy should stimulate private investments and thus bringing Sp
– I
close to zero. There
are several
policy
options being consistent with the algebra of the accounting system.
By
the way: in some texts there is confusion about the term “surplus”
which is sometimes identified with savings which requires “debt”
of another entity. That’s wrong. Example:
zero public and private household savings, zero net exports, but
firms have positive savings which are equivalent to their own net
investment. No
debt is involved.
6)
MMT
rejects the idea of crowding
out. Crowding out only happens if the economy is at it’s capacity
limits.
It
is argued that there cannot be an interest-rate based crowding out
effect as the interest rate is controlled by the CB.
A crowding out by deficit spending because placing new sovereign
bonds in the market will reduce private financing – both are
competing for saver’s funds – is also rejected. Public spending
financed by the money press will not reduce the demand for corporate
bonds.
Moreover, private activities could be easily financed by fully
elastic credit supply. True,
but if public debt is not
monetized, and if credit supply isn’t
fully elastic, the argument does not hold. In addition, many
MMT
proponents argue that aggregate demand does not depend on the real
interest rate (vertical
IS curve).
Henceforth, even increasing long-term
rates will not have a dampening effect. The
reason why aggregate demand is not tied to the interest rate (no
intertemporal deliberations of consumers/savers and investors at all?
Really?)
remain unclear. So the problem of potential crowding out is more or
less assumed away by
declaring all
possible economic transmission channels as being irrelevant or
inexistent.
The
atitude is not to
say: yes, there are multiple
potential economic mechanisms, but I consider them as empirically
less relevant. Instead, the attitude is more apodictic: it’s
not just
empirical evidence, it’s
a deep theoretical insight.
The
numerous econometric estimates of fiscal multipliers which should be
quite large in absence of any crowding out effects, but in
fact turned
out to be relatively small, seem not to be well recognized.
By
the way, if aggregate demand does not depend on the interest rate,
there is not much room for
interest-rate based monetary
policy to stimulate aggregate demand like
in mainstream models.
The
main transmission channel is simply regarded as being inexistent.
Monetary
policy becomes ineffective and has to be replaced by fiscal policy.
It
just serves as an “assistant” for the fiscal authority. But then
the question arises, if this is really true, why do
central banks then accomodate
each reserve demand in order to keep control over the interest rate?
If this ttransmission
channel is
inexistent?
I
can imagine the answer: because they are believing in the wrong
mainstream model. But
then central banks believing in and acting according to a “wrong”
model are a cornerstone of the “correct” MMT model?
7)
MMT
largely rejects the Phillips Curve.
So
all attempts for detalied (micro-) economic explanations of this
curve
are simply wiped away as being irrelevant. Also empirical evidence
about ties between output and inflation is irgnored. It is a general
and very remarkable attitude of MMT and also (largely) PK economics
that there is a lack of deliberated and diligent econometric
analysis. While in the last decades “evidence based”
macroeconomics got
growing importance (and thus being much more flexible with respect to
“ideological” positions), MMT/PK publications
often
look at
aggregated macroeconomic time series by eye-balling, seeking for
evidence confrming their narratives. I wouldn’t regard that as
empirical
research
on a competitive level. Perhaps
I am wrong, I am not an expert in this field, but I still haven’t
found somebody to convince me about the opposite.
Once
when the Phillips Curve is rejected, life becomes very easy: as there
is no goal conflict between unemployment and inflation any longer,
also the time-inconsistency and agency problems which lead to the
central bank independence literature can be happily
ignored.
Without goal conflicts, we also do not need a solution of the
assignment problem, so why not
bundling fiscal and monetary policy to one unit? This
isn’t a highly problematic vision any longer once when we have
assumed away all severe problems this might induce.
If
there is no Phillips Curve trade-off, and the fiscal budget is not
constrained, any measures of deficit-spending at any size could be
recommended in order to bring down unemployment. Very
easy! And
if inflation starts to rise, MMT suggests to rise taxes which then
reduces the money stock (see point 2). Henceforth, fiscal policy is
assigned to both targets, employment and price stability, while
monetary policy just accomodates it. The interesting point is that
this establishes a strong tie between money and inflation likewise in
the quantity equation approach. But in contrast to the monetarist
approach, MMT suggests that money
creation (for fiscal reasons) do have a real effect on the output. I
would see here a slight contradition to the money
endogeneity
approach where the causality runs from output and price level to
money demand and thus money supply, rather than from money supply to
output
and price
level.
8) Parts of MMT
suggests a public job guarantee. The government could hire any amount
of workers until the capacity limits are reached.
Payment of these workers (usually minimum wages) isn’t a problem
because the governmental budget is not constrained. In
case of need, it is financed by the central bank.
This is clearly not
“theory” but a (left) political agenda. All problems associated
with such a program (e.g. crowding out private competitors) should
not be discussed here. My aim is just to discuss the status as a
valuable theory.
Summing up, there are some valuable insights, i.e. point 1), but they are mainstream and widely accepted. There are also interesting insights into practical ties between fiscal and monetary operations, see point 2), which deserve more attention, although I don’t believe that fundamental theoretical insights can be derived from that. Even the highly critical point 3) could be fruitful if communicated in a much less doctrinaire manner. Nobody will be willing to recognize arguments speaking in favor of e.g. an arrangement where the CB is allowed to buy public debt on the primary market without any danger of moral hazard or fiscal dominance (e.g. as a standard procedure to create reserves such that the interest rate goal is achieved), or allowing CB to be the lender of last resort, if one either has to decide to remain a “mainstream enemy” or to convert to the gospel truth of an MMT cult. There are too many aspects of the new “paradigm” which makes it scientifically non-competitive. Therefore, MMT should not set hope on a “paradigm shift”. I am more in favor of Imre Lakatos’ concept of a research program where the core of the program could change due to a rational discussion of arguments. But then a lot has to be changed in communication and wording. In my personal view, the mainstream can learn much more from PK’s ideas of effective demand, fundamental uncertainty, and heuristic behavior rather than from MMT.